Tuesday, May 21, 2019
Role of Computer in Daily Life
pecuniary Crises and coast liquid Creation Allen N. Berger and Christa H. S. Bouwman October 2008 Financial crises and brink runniness population argon genuinely much connected. We probe this connexion from twain perspectives. First, we examine the essence liquifiedity conception of margeing concerns forwardshand, during, and by and by tailfin major fiscal crises in the U. S. from 1984Q1 to 2008Q1. We unc solely oer numerous rice beering patterns, much(prenominal) as a significant build-up or drop-off of insane fluidness understructure forrader each crisis, where ab rule is defined relative to a time class and seasonal factors. hopeing and merchandise-related crises differ in that chamfering crises were preceded by anomalous positive runniness intromission, go marketplace-related crises were gener onlyy preceded by deviant negative fluidity unveiling. margin fluidness worldly concern has two decreased and reassign magnitude during cris es, in completely probability both exacerbating and ameliorating the personal answers of crises. Off-balance stable gear guarantees such as add commitments travel to a greater extent than on-balance opinion poll assets such as mortgages and military get wind alter during tilling crises.Second, we examine the effect of pre-crisis coin bound great ratios on the competitive military positions and favor sufficientness of individual banks during and aft(prenominal) each crisis. The evidence suggests that juicy jacket served thumping banks wholesome most banking crises they meliorated their fluidity knowledgeability market sh atomic number 18 and advantageousness during these crises and were able to piddle on to their improved bring aboutance later onwardswards. In addition, lifts- swell listed banks enjoyed importantly mellower affected demarcation returns than low- majuscule listed banks during banking crises.These benefits did not hold or held to a less er degree around marketrelated crises and in normal quantify. In contrast, gritty great(p) ratios seem to boast helped pocket-sized banks improve their smoothity basis market sh ar during banking crises, market-related crises, and normal times a want, and the gains in market sh be were buzz offed by and bywards. Their positivity improved during ii crises and subsequent to virtu everyy either crisis. equal results were observed during normal times for minuscular banks. University of s emergeheastward Carolina, Wharton Financial Institutions Center, and CentER Tilburg University.Contact details Moore shallow of Business, University of South Carolina, 1705 College Street, Columbia, SC 29208. Tel 803-576-8440. Fax 803-777-6876. E-mail emailprotected sc. edu. Case Western Reserve University, and Wharton Financial Institutions Center. Contact details Weatherhead School of Management, Case Western Reserve University, 10900 Euclid Avenue, 362 PBL, Cleveland, OH 44106. Te l. 216-368-3688. Fax 216-368-6249. E-mail christa. emailprotected edu. Keywords Financial Crises, Liquidity Creation, and Banking. JEL Classifi twation G28, and G21.The authors thank Asani Sarkar, tail DeYoung, Peter Ritchken, Greg Udell, and participants at presentations at the Summer Research Conference 2008 in Finance at the ISB in Hyderabad, the International Mo plunderary Fund, the University of Kansas Southwind Finance Conference, and Erasmus University for partful comments. Financial Crises and Bank Liquidity Creation 1. Introduction everywhere the one-time(prenominal) dope century, the U. S. has experienced a number of fiscal crises. At the heart of these crises atomic number 18 often issues surrounding runniness provision by the banking sector and financial markets (e. . , Acharya, Shin, and Yorulmazer 2007). For example, in the live subprime lend crisis, fluidness seems to get hold of dried up as banks seem less willing to lend to individuals, firms, anot her(prenominal) banks, and capital market participants, and loan securitization appears to be significantly depressed. This fashion of banks is summarized by the Economist Although bankers be always stingier in a downturn, lots of banks said they had also cut back lending because of a slide in their current or expected capital and liquid. 1 The practical importance of liquidness during crises is scarcetressed by financial intermediation theory, which expresss that the human race of liquid is an important reason why banks exist. 2 Early contri thoions vie that banks create runniness by financing relatively illiquid assets such as business loans with relatively liquid liabilities such as proceeding deposits (e. g. , Bryant 1980, Diamond and Dybvig 1983). More recent contributions suggest that banks also create liquid off the balance bed rag through loan commitments and similar claims to liquid funds (e. g. Holmstrom and Tirole 1998, Kashyap, Rajan, and Stein 2002). 3 The mankind of fluidity makes banks fragile and susceptible to runs (e. g. , Diamond and Dybvig 1983, Chari and Jagannathan 1988), and such runs can lead to crises via contagion effects. Bank runniness psychiatric hospital can also suck tangible effects, in particular if a financial crisis ruptures the creation of liquid state (e. g. , dellAriccia, Detragiache, and Rajan 2008). 4 Exploring the relationship surrounded by financial crises and bank liquidness creation can consequently prod all everywhere authorisationly interesting scotch insights and may have important constitution impli regorgeions.The stopping points of this musical composition are twofold. The setoff is to examine the aggregate fluidity creation of 1 The acknowledgement crisis Financial engine failure The Economist, February 7, 2008. According to the theory, another central role of banks in the economy is to transform reference book risk (e. g. , Diamond 1984, Ramakrishnan and Thakor 1984, Boyd and Prescott 1986). Recently, Coval and Thakor (2005) theorize that banks may also arise in response to the conduct of anomalous agents in financial markets. 3James (1981) and Boot, Thakor, and Udell (1991) endogenize the loan commitment contract due to informational frictions. The loan commitment contract is afterwardsward used in Holmstrom and Tirole (1998) and Kashyap, Rajan, and Stein (2002) to show how banks can translate liquidness to borrowers. 4 Acharya and Pedersen (2005) show that fluidity risk also affects the expected returns on strains. 2 1 banks around five financial crises in the U. S. over the past quarter century. 5 The crises include two banking crises (the ac honorable mention make noise of the early mid-nineties and the subprime lending crisis of 2007 ? and leash crises that can be viewed as primarily market-related (the 1987 stock market crash, the Russian debt crisis positively charged the long-term Capital Management meltdown in 1998, and the bursting of the dot. com spew out asset the September 11 terrorist flack of the early 2000s). This examination is intended to shed light on whether on that point are any connections surrounded by financial crises and aggregate runniness creation, and whether these vary ground on the nature of the crisis (i. e. , banking versus market-related crisis). A good nderstanding of the carriage of bank liquidity creation around financial crises is also important to shed light on whether banks create likewise itsy-bitsy or too much liquidity, and whether bank port exacerbates or amelio ordains the effects of crises. We document the a posteriori regularities related to these issues, so as to raise additional interesting questions for further empirical and theoretical examinations. The second goal is to study the effect of pre-crisis righteousness capital ratios on the competitive positions and favorableness of individual banks around each crisis.Since bank capital affects liquid ity creation (e. g. , Diamond and Rajan 2000, 2001, Berger and Bouwman forthcoming), it is in all probability that banks with unalike capital ratios behave differently during crises in follow of their liquidity creation responses. Specifically, we ask are high-capital banks able to gain market share in hurt of liquidity creation at the expense of low-capital banks during a crisis, and does such enhanced market share translate into higher lucrativeness? If so, are the high-capital banks able to sustain their improved competitive positions after the financial crisis is over?The recent acquisitions of Countrywide, Bear Stearns, and Washington Mutual provide interesting case studies in this regard. All three firms ran low on capital and had to be bailed out by banks with stronger capital positions. Bank of America (Countrywides acquirer) and J. P. Morgan Chase (acquirer of Bear-Stearns and Washington Mutuals banking operations) had capital ratios high enough to enable them to buy their rivals at a runty member of what they were worth a year beforehand, thereby gaining a potential competitive advantage. 6 The recent experience of IndyMac Bank provides 5Studies on the behavior of banks around financial crises have typically contracted on mercantile and real soil lending (e. g. , Berger and Udell 1994, Hancock, Laing, and Wilcox 1995, DellAriccia, Igan, and Laeven 2008). We focus on the more comprehensive notion of bank liquidity creation. 6 On Sunday, March 16, 2008, J. P. Morgan Chase agreed to pay $2 a share to buy all of Bear Stearns, less than unrivaledtenth of the firms share price on Friday and a diminutive fraction of the $170 share price a year before. On March 24, 2008, it plusd its bid to $10, and immaculate the transaction on May 30, 2008.On January 11, Bank of America announced it would pay $4 billion for Countrywide, after Countrywides market capitalization had plummeted 85% during the preceding 12 months. The transaction was completed on July 1, 2008. later on a $16. 4 billion ten-day bank 2 another interesting example. The FDIC seized IndyMac Bank after it suffered substantive losses and depositors had started to run on the bank. The FDIC intends to cuckold the bank, preferably as a single entity but if that does not work, the bank will be sell off in pieces.Given the way the regulatory cheering process for bank acquisitions works, it is likely that the acquirer(s) will have a strong capital base. 7 A financial crisis is a natural event to examine how capital affects the competitive positions of banks. During normal times, capital has some effects on the bank, some of which counteract each other, making it difficult to learn much. For example, capital helps the bank cope more effectively with risk,8 but it also reduces the value of the deposit insurance put preference (Merton 1977). During a crisis, risks become elevated and the risk-absorption capacity of capital becomes par essence.Banks with high capita l, which are better buffered against the shocks of the crisis, may thus gain a potential advantage. To examine the behavior of bank liquidity creation around financial crises, we think the measuring stick of liquidity created by the banking sector utilize Berger and Bouwmans (forthcoming) preferred liquidity creation measure. This measure takes into account the fact that banks create liquidity both on and off the balance tabloid and is constructed utilise a three-step mathematical operation. In the runner step, all bank assets, liabilities, equity, and off-balance sheet activities are classified as liquid, semi-liquid, or illiquid.This is done found on the ease, cost, and time for customers to obtain liquid funds from the bank, and the ease, cost, and time for banks to jail of their obligations in order to make full these liquidity demands. This classification process uses information on both harvest category and maturity for all activities other than loans due to data li mitations, loans are classified base solely on category (cat). Thus, residential mortgages are classified as more liquid than business loans regardless of maturity because it is generally easier to securitize and get by such mortgages than business loans.In the second step, w octettes are depute to these activities. The weights are undifferentiated with the theory in that maximum liquidity is created when illiquid assets (e. g. , business loans) are transformed into liquid liabilities (e. g. , transactions deposits) and maximum liquidity is annuled when liquid assets (e. g. , treasuries) are transformed into illiquid liabilities walk, Washington Mutual was situated into the receivership of the FDIC on September 25, 2008. J. P. Morgan Chase purchased the banking business for $1. 9 billion and re-opened the bank the next day.On September 26, 2008, the prop guild and its remaining subsidiary filed for bankruptcy. Washington Mutual, the sixth- largishst bank in the U. S. before its collapse, is the largest bank failure in the U. S. financial history. 7 After peaking at $50. 11 on May 8, 2006, IndyMacs shares lost 87% of their value in 2007 and another 95% in 2008. Its share price closed at $0. 28 on July 11, 2008, the day before it was seized by the FDIC. 8 There are numerous written document that cope that capital enhances the risk-absorption capacity of banks (e. g. , Bhattacharya and Thakor 1993, Repullo 2004, Von Thadden 2004). (e. g. , subordinated debt) or equity. In the third step, a cat copious liquidity creation measure is constructed, where fat refers to the inclusion of off-balance sheet activities. Although Berger and Bouwman construct four different liquidity creation measures, they indicate that cat fat is the preferred measure. They argue that to assess the follow of liquidity creation, the ability to securitize or sell a particular loan category is more important than the maturity of those loans, and the inclusion of off-balance sheet a ctivities is fine. We check the cat fat liquidity creation measure to quarterly data on virtually all U. S. moneymaking(prenominal) and assent card banks from 1984Q1 to 2008Q1. Our measurement of aggregate liquidity creation by banks allows us to examine the behavior of liquidity created prior to, during, and after each crisis. The popular press has provided anecdotal accounts of liquidity drying up during some financial crises as well as excessive liquidity provision at other times that led to assent expansion ruffles (e. g. , the subprime lending crisis).We attempt to give empirical content to these notions of too little and too much liquidity created by banks. Liquidity creation has quadrupled in real terms over the try on period and appears to have seasonal components (as documented at a lower place). Since no theories exist that explain the intertemporal behavior of liquidity creation, we take an essentially empirical snuggle to the problem and focus on how far liquidi ty creation lies to a higher place or below a time trend and seasonal factors. 10 That is, we focus on abnormal liquidity creation.The use of this measure rests on the supposition that some normal summation of liquidity creation exists, acknowledging that at any point in time, liquidity creation may be too much or too little in horse terms. Our main results regarding the behavior of liquidity creation around financial crises are as follows. First, prior to financial crises, there seems to have been a significant build-up or drop-off of abnormal liquidity creation. Second, banking and market-related crises differ in two respects.The banking crises (the credit crunch of 1990-1992 and the current subprime lending crisis) were preceded by abnormal positive liquidity creation by banks, whereas the market-related crises were generally preceded by abnormal negative liquidity creation. In addition, the banking crises themselves seemed to change the trajectory of aggregate liquidity creat ion, while the market-related crises did not appear to do so. Third, 9 Their alternative measures include cat nonfat, mat fat, and mat nonfat. The nonfat measures stave off offbalance sheet activities, and the mat measures distinguish loans by maturity quite an than by product category. 0 As alternative approaches, we use the sawbuck bill sum of liquidity creation per capita and liquidity creation dissever by gross domestic product and obtain similar results (see ingredient 4. 2). 4 liquidity creation has both decreased during crises (e. g. , the 1990-1992 credit crunch) and increased during crises (e. g. , the 1998 Russian debt crisis / LTCM bailout). Thus, liquidity creation likely both exacerbated and ameliorated the effects of crises. Fourth, off-balance sheet illiquid guarantees (primarily loan commitments) getd more than semi-liquid assets (primarily mortgages) and illiquid assets (primarily business loans) during banking crises.Fifth, the current subprime lending c risis was preceded by an unusually high positive abnormal amount of aggregate liquidity creation, possibly caused by lax lending standards that led banks to extend increasing amounts of credit and off-balance sheet guarantees. This suggests a possible dark side of bank liquidity creation. small-arm financial discretion may be needed to induce banks to create liquidity (e. g. , Diamond and Rajan 2000, 2001), our analysis raises the intriguing speculation that the causality may also be reversed in the sense that too much liquidity creation may lead to financial fragility.We then turn to the second goal of the paper examining whether banks pre-crisis capital ratios affect their competitive positions and profitability around financial crises. To examine the effect on a banks competitive position, we regress the change in its market share of liquidity creation heedful as the comely market share of aggregate liquidity creation during the crisis (or over the eight billet after the crisis) minus the average market share over the eight canton before the crisis, convey as a proportion of the banks average pre-crisis market share on its average pre-crisis capital ratio and a set of control variables. 1 Since the analyses in the first half of the paper reveal a great deal of heterogeneity in crises, we run these regressions on a per-crisis basis, rather than pooling the data across crises. The control variables include bank size, bank risk, bank holding caller membership, topical anaesthetic market competition,12 and proxies for the economic circumstances in the local markets in which the bank operates. Moreover, we examine large and small banks as two separate groups since the results in Berger and Bouwman (forthcoming) indicate that the effect of capital on liquidity creation differs across large and small banks. 13 11Defining market share this way is a departure from anterior research (e. g. , Laeven and Levine 2007), in which market share relates to the banks weighted-average local market share of nub deposits. 12 trance our focus is on the change in banks competitive positions heedful in terms of their aggregate liquidity creation market shares, we control for local market competition measured as the bank-level Herfindahl index based on local market deposit market shares. 13 Berger and Bouwman use three size categories large, medium, and small banks. We combine the large and medium bank categories into one large bank category. 5One potential concern is that differences in bank capital ratios may simply reflect differences in bank risk. Banks that hold higher capital ratios because their investment portfolios are riskier may not improve their competitive positions around financial crises. Our empirical design takes this into account. The inclusion of bank risk as a control variable is critical and ensures that the measured effect of capital on a banks market share is net of the effect of risk. We find evidence that high-capital large banks improved their market share of liquidity creation during the two banking crises, but not during the market-related crises.After the credit crunch of the early 1990s, high-capital large banks held on to their improved competitive positions. Since the current subprime lending crisis was not over at the end of the ideal period, we cannot yet tell whether highcapital large banks will also hold on to their improved competitive positions after this crisis. In contrast to the large banks, high-capital small banks seemed to enhance their competitive positions during all crises and held on to their improved competitive positions after the crises as well.Next, we focus on the effect of pre-crisis bank capital on the profitability of the bank around each crisis. We run regressions that are similar to the ones suck upd above with the change in return on equity ( roe) as the interdependent variable. We find that high-capital large banks improved their ROE in those cases in which t hey enhanced their liquidity creation market share the two banking crises and were able to hold on to their improved profitability after the credit crunch. profitability after the market-related crises. They also increased theirIn contrast, for high-capital small banks, profitability improved during two crises, and subsequent to virtually every crisis. As an additional analysis, we examine whether the improved competitive positions and profitability of high-capital banks translated into better stock return performance. To perform this analysis, we focus on listed banks and bank holding companies (BHCs). If multiple banks are part of the same listed BHC, their financial statements are added together to create pro-forma financial statements of the BHC.The results confirm the earlier change in performance findings of large banks listed banks with high capital ratios enjoyed significantly larger abnormal returns than banks with low capital ratios during banking crises, but not during market-related crises. Our results are based on a five-factor asset pricing model that includes the three Fama-French (1993) factors, momentum, and a proxy for the slope of the yield curve. 6 We also check whether high capital provided similar advantages outside crisis periods, i. e. , during normal times.We find that large banks with high capital ratios did not enjoy either market share or profitability gains over the other large banks, whereas for small banks, results are similar to the smallbank findings hold forthed above. Moreover, outside banking crises, high capital was not associated with high stock returns. Combined, the results suggest that high capital ratios serve large banks well, particularly around banking crises. In contrast, high capital ratios appear to help small banks around banking crises, marketrelated crises, and normal times alike. The remainder of this paper is form as follows.Section 2 discusses the related literature. Section 3 explains the liquidity cre ation measures and our attempt based on data of U. S. banks from 1984Q1 to 2008Q1. Section 4 describes the behavior of aggregate bank liquidity creation around five financial crises and draws some general conclusions. Section 5 discusses the tests of the effects of precrisis capital ratios on banks competitive positions and profitability around financial crises and normal times. This section also examines the stock returns of high- and low-capital listed banking arrangements during each crisis and during normal times. Section 6 concludes. 2. Related literature This paper is related to two literatures. The first is the literature on financial crises. 14 One strand in this literature has focused on financial crises and fragility. about papers have testd contagion. Contributions in this area suggest that a small liquidity shock in one area may have a contagious effect throughout the economy (e. g. , Allen and Gale 1998, 2000). Other papers have focused on the determinants of finan cial crises and the policy implications (e. g. Bordo, Eichengreen, Klingebiel, and Martinez-Peria 2001, Demirguc-Kunt, Detragiache, and Gupta 2006, Lorenzoni 2008, Claessens, Klingebiel, and Laeven forthcoming). A second strand examines the effect of financial crises on the real sector (e. g. , Friedman and Schwarz 1963, Bernanke 1983, Bernanke and Gertler 1989, DellAriccia, Detragiache, and Rajan 2008, Shin forthcoming). These papers find that financial crises increase the cost of financing and reduce credit, which adversely affects corporate investment and may lead to reduced 14Allen and Gale (2007) provide a detailed overview of the causes and consequences of financial crises. 7 goth and recessions. That is, financial crises have independent real effects (see DellAriccia, Detragiache, and Rajan 2008). In contrast to these papers, we examine how the amount of liquidity created by the banking sector behaved around financial crises in the U. S. , and explore systematic patterns in the data. The second literature to which this paper is related focuses on the strategic use of leverage in product-market competition for non-financial firms (e. g. , Brander and Lewis 1986, Campello 2006, Lyandres 2006).This literature suggests that financial leverage can affect competitive dynamics. While this literature has not focused on banks, we analyze the effects of crises on the competitive positioning and profitability of banks based on their pre-crisis capital ratios. Our hypothesis is that in the case of banks, the competitive implications of capital are likely to be most pronounced during a crisis when a banks capitalization has a major square up on its ability to survive the crisis, particularly in light of regulatory discretion in closing banks or otherwise resolving problem institutions.Liquidity creation may be a rail line through which this competitive advantage is gained or lost. 15 3. Description of the liquidity creation measure and sample We head the dollar amount of liquidity created by the banking sector using Berger and Bouwmans (forthcoming) preferred cat fat liquidity creation measure. In this section, we explain briefly what this acronym stands for and how we construct this measure. 16 We then describe our sample. All financial values are expressed in real 2007Q4 dollars using the implicit gross domestic product price deflator. 3. 1. Liquidity creation measureTo construct a measure of liquidity creation, we follow Berger and Bouwmans three-step procedure (see Table 1). Below, we briefly discuss these three steps. In Step 1, we classify all bank activities (assets, liabilities, equity, and off-balance sheet activities) as liquid, semi-liquid, or illiquid. For assets, we do this based on the ease, cost, and time for banks to dispose of their obligations in order to meet these liquidity demands. For liabilities and equity, we do this 15 Allen and Gale (2004) analyze how competition affects financial stability. We reverse the causali ty and examine the effect of financial crises on competition. 6 For a more detailed discussion, see Berger and Bouwman (forthcoming). 8 based on the ease, cost, and time for customers to obtain liquid funds from the bank. We follow a similar approach for off-balance sheet activities, classifying them based on functionally similar on-balance sheet activities. For all activities other than loans, this classification process uses information on both product category and maturity. Due to data restrictions, we classify loans entirely by category (cat). 17 In Step 2, we assign weights to all the bank activities classified in Step 1.The weights are consistent with liquidity creation theory, which argues that banks create liquidity on the balance sheet when they transform illiquid assets into liquid liabilities. We therefore apply positive weights to illiquid assets and liquid liabilities. Following similar logic, we apply negative weights to liquid assets and illiquid liabilities and equit y, since banks destroy liquidity when they use illiquid liabilities to finance liquid assets. We use weights of ? and -? , because only half of the come amount of liquidity created is attributable to the source or use of funds alone.For example, when $1 of liquid liabilities is used to finance $1 in illiquid assets, liquidity creation equals ? * $1 + ? * $1 = $1. In this case, maximum liquidity is created. However, when $1 of liquid liabilities is used to finance $1 in liquid assets, liquidity creation equals ? * $1 + -? * $1 = $0. In this case, no liquidity is created as the bank holds items of approximately the same liquidity as those it gives to the nonbank public. Maximum liquidity is destroyed when $1 of illiquid liabilities or equity is used to finance $1 of liquid assets. In this case, liquidity creation equals -? $1 + -? * $1 = -$1. An intermediate weight of 0 is applied to semi-liquid assets and liabilities. Weights for off-balance sheet activities are assigned using the s ame principles. In Step 3, we combine the activities as classified in Step 1 and as weighted in Step 2 to construct Berger and Bouwmans preferred cat fat liquidity creation measure. This measure classifies loans by category (cat), while all activities other than loans are classified using information on product category and maturity, and includes off-balance sheet activities (fat).Berger and Bouwman construct four liquidity creation measures by alternatively classifying loans by category or maturity, and by alternatively including or excluding off-balance sheet activities. However, they argue that cat fat is the preferred measure since for liquidity creation, banks ability to securitize or sell loans is more important than loan maturity, and banks do create liquidity both on the balance sheet and off the balance sheet. 17 Alternatively, we could classify loans by maturity (mat).However, Berger and Bouwman argue that it is preferable to classify them by category since for loans, the ability to securitize or sell is more important than their maturity. 9 To obtain the dollar amount of liquidity creation at a particular bank, we multiply the weights of ? , -? , or 0, respectively, times the dollar amounts of the corresponding bank activities and add the weighted dollar amounts. 3. 2. Sample description We include virtually all commercial and credit card banks in the U. S. in our study. 18 For each bank, we obtain quarterly look to Report data from 1984Q1 to 2008Q1.We keep a bank if it 1) has commercial real estate or commercial and industrial loans outstanding 2) has deposits 3) has an equity capital ratio of at least 1% 4) has gross total assets or GTA (total assets plus fee for loan and lease losses and the allocated transfer risk reserve) exceeding $25 one thousand thousand. We end up with data on 18,134 distinct banks, yielding 907,159 bank-quarter observations over our sample period. For each bank, we calculate the dollar amount of liquidity creation using the process described in Section 3. 1.The amount of liquidity creation and all other financial values are put into real 2007Q4 dollars using the implicit GDP price deflator. When we explore aggregate bank liquidity creation around financial crises, we focus on the real dollar amount of liquidity creation by the banking sector. To obtain this, we aggregate the liquidity created by all banks in each quarter and end up with a sample that contains 97 inflation-adjusted, quarterly liquidity creation amounts. In contrast, when we examine how capital affects the competitive positions of banks, we focus on the amount of liquidity created by individual banks around each crisis.Given documented differences between large and small banks in terms of portfolio composition (e. g. , Kashyap, Rajan, and Stein 2002, Berger, Miller, Petersen, Rajan, and Stein 2005) and the effect of capital on liquidity creation (Berger and Bouwman forthcoming), we split the sample into large banks (between 330 and 4 77 observations, depending on the crisis) and small banks (between 5556 and 6343 observations, depending on the crisis), and run all change in market share and profitability regressions separately for these two sets of banks.Large banks have gross total assets (GTA) exceeding $1 billion at the end of the quarter before a crisis 18 Berger and Bouwman (forthcoming) include only commercial banks. We also include credit card banks to avoid an artificial $0. 19 trillion drop in bank liquidity creation in the fourth quarter of 2006 when Citibank N. A. moved its credit-card lines to Citibank South Dakota N. A. , a credit card bank. 10 and small banks have GTA up to $1 billion at the end of that quarter. 19,20 4.The behavior of aggregate bank liquidity creation around financial crises This section focuses on the first goal of the paper examining the aggregate liquidity creation of banks across five financial crises in the U. S. over the past quarter century. The crises include the 1987 sto ck market crash, the credit crunch of the early 1990s, the Russian debt crisis plus Long-Term Capital Management (LTCM) bailout of 1998, the bursting of the dot. com bubble and the Sept. 11 terrorist attacks of the early 2000s, and the current subprime lending crisis. We first provide heavyset statistics and explain our empirical approach.We then discuss alternative measures of abnormal liquidity creation. Next, we describe the behavior of bank liquidity creation before, during, and after each crisis. Finally, we draw some general conclusions from these results. 4. 1. Summary statistics and empirical approach propose 1 grace A shows the dollar amount of liquidity created by the banking sector, calculated using the cat fat liquidity creation measure over our sample period. As shown, liquidity creation has increased self-coloredly over time it has more than quadrupled from $1. 369 trillion in 1984Q1 to $5. 06 trillion in 2008Q1 (in real 2007Q4 dollars). We want to examine whether liquidity creation by the banking sector is high, low, or at a normal level around financial crises. Since no theories exist that explain the intertemporal behavior of liquidity creation or generate numerical estimates of normal liquidity creation, we need a reasonable empirical approach. At first blush, it may seem that we could simply calculate the average amount of bank liquidity creation over the entire sample period and view amounts above this sample average as high and amounts below the average as low. However, inning 1 jury A clearly shows that this approach would cause us to classify the entire second half of the sample period (1996Q1 2008Q1) as high and the entire first half of the sample period (1984Q1 1995Q4) as low. We therefore do not 19 As famous before, we combine Berger and Bouwmans large and medium bank categories into one large bank category. Recall that all financial values are expressed in real 2007Q4 dollars. 20 GTA equals total assets plus the allowance f or loan and lease losses and the allocated transfer risk reserve.Total assets on Call Reports deduct these two reserves, which are held to cover potential credit losses. We add these reserves back to measure the full value of the loans financed and the liquidity created by the bank on the asset side. 11 use this approach. The approach we take is aimed at calculating the abnormal amount of liquidity created by the banking sector based on a time trend. It focuses on whether liquidity creation lies above or below this time trend, and also deseasonalizes the data to ensure that we do not base our conclusions on mere seasonal effects.We detrend and deseasonalize the data by regressing the dollar amount of liquidity creation on a time index and three quarterly dummies. The residuals from this regression measure the abnormal dollar amount of liquidity creation in a particular quarter. That is, they measure how far (deseasonalized) liquidity creation lies above or below the trend line. If abnormal liquidity creation is greater than (smaller than) $0, the dollar amount of liquidity created by the banking sector lies above (below) the time trend.If abnormal liquidity creation is high (low) relative to the time trend and seasonal factors, we will transform this as liquidity creation be too high (too low). Figure 1 Panel B shows abnormal liquidity creation over time. The amount of liquidity created by the banking sector was high (yet declining) in the mid-1980s, low in the mid-1990s, and high (and mostly rising) in the most recent years. 4. 2. Alternative measures of abnormal liquidity creation We considered some(prenominal) alternative approaches to measuring abnormal liquidity creation. One surmisal is to scale the dollar amount of liquidity creation by total population.The idea behind this approach is that a normal amount of liquidity creation may exist in per capita terms. The average amount of liquidity creation per capita over our sample period could potentiall y serve as the normal amount and deviations from this average would be viewed as abnormal. To calculate per capita liquidity creation we obtain annual U. S. population estimates from the U. S. Census Bureau. Figure 2 Panel A shows per capita liquidity creation over time. The hand over reveals that per capita liquidity creation more than tripled from $5. 8K in 1984Q1 to $18. 8K in 2008Q1.Interestingly, the picture looks very similar to the one shown in Panel A, perhaps because the annual U. S. population growth rate is low. For reasons similar to those in our earlier analysis, we calculate abnormal per capita liquidity creation by detrending and deseasonalizing the data like we did in the previous section. Figure 2 Panel B shows abnormal per capita liquidity creation over time. 12 Another possibility is to scale the dollar amount of liquidity creation by GDP. Since liquidity creation by banks may causally affect GDP, this approach seems less appropriate.Nonetheless, we show the resu lts for completeness. Figure 2 Panel C shows the dollar amount of liquidity creation single out by GDP. The picture reveals that bank liquidity creation has increased from 19. 9% of GDP in 1984Q1 to 40. 4% of GDP in 2008Q1. While liquidity creation more than quadrupled over the sample period, GDP doubled. Importantly, the picture looks similar to the one shown in Panel A. Again, for reasons similar to those in our earlier analysis, we detrend and deseasonalize the data to obtain abnormal liquidity creation divided by GDP.Figure 2 Panel D shows abnormal liquidity creation divided by GDP over time. Since these alternative approaches yield results that are similar to those shown in Section 4. 1, we focus our discussions on the abnormal amount of liquidity creation (rather than the abnormal amount of per capita liquidity creation or the abnormal amount of liquidity creation divided by GDP) around financial crises. 4. 3. Abnormal bank liquidity creation before, during, and after five f inancial crises We now examine how abnormal bank liquidity creation behaved efore, during, and after five financial crises. In all cases, the pre-crisis and post-crisis periods are defined to be eight lodge long. 21 The one exception is that we do not examine abnormal bank liquidity creation after the current subprime lending crisis, since this crisis was still ongoing at the end of the sample period. Figure 3 Panels A E show the graphs of the abnormal amount of liquidity creation for the five crises. This subsection is a investigative effort and largely descriptive. In Section 4. , we will combine the evidence gathered here and interpret it to draw some general conclusions. Financial crisis 1 Stock market crash (1987Q4) On Monday, October 19, 1987, the stock market crashed, with the S&P500 index falling about 20%. During the years before the crash, the level of the stock market had increased dramatically, causing some 21 As a result of our choice of biennial pre-crisis and post -crisis periods, the post-Russian debt crisis period overlaps with the bursting of the dot. com bubble, and the pre-dot. com bubble period overlaps with the Russian debt crisis.For these two crises, we redo our analyses using six-quarter pre-crisis and post-crisis periods and obtain results that are qualitatively similar to the ones documented here. 13 concern that the market had become overvalued. 22 A few age before the crash, two events occurred that may have helped precipitate the crash 1) legislation was enacted to eliminate certain tax revenue benefits associated with financing mergers and 2) information was released that the trade deficit was above expectations. Both events seemed to have added to the selling pressure and a record trading volume on Oct. 9, in part caused by program trading, overwhelmed legion(predicate) systems. Figure 3 Panel A shows abnormal bank liquidity creation before, during, and after the stock market crash. Although this financial crisis seems to have originated in the stock market rather than the banking system, it is clear from the graph that abnormal liquidity creation by banks was high ($0. 5 trillion above the time trend) two years before the crisis. It had already dropped substantially before the crisis and continued to drop until well after the crisis, but was still above the time trend even a year after the crisis.Financial crisis 2 Credit crunch (1990Q1 1992Q4) During the first three years of the 1990s, bank commercial and industrial lending declined in real terms, particularly for small banks and for small loans (see Berger, Kashyap, and Scalise 1995, Table 8, for details). The ascribed causes of the credit crunch include a fall in bank capital from the loan loss experiences of the late 1980s (e. g. , Peek and Rosengren 1995), the increases in bank leverage enquirements and implementation of Basel I risk-based capital standards during this time period (e. g. Berger and Udell 1994, Hancock, Laing, and Wilcox 1995, Thakor 1996), an increase in supervisory toughness evidenced in worse examination ratings for a given bank condition (e. g. , Berger, Kyle, and Scalise 2001), and reduced loan demand because of macroeconomic and regional recessions (e. g. , Bernanke and Lown 1991). To some extent, the research supports virtually all of these hypotheses. Figure 3 Panel B shows how abnormal liquidity creation behaved before, during, and after the credit crunch. The graph shows that liquidity creation was above the time trend before the crisis, but declining.After a temporary increase, it dropped markedly during the crisis by roughly $0. 6 trillion, and the decline even widen a bit beyond the crunch period. After having reached a noticeably low level in the post-crunch period, liquidity creation slack offly started to bottom out. This evidence suggests that the 22 E. g. , Raging bull, stock markets surge is puzzling investors When will it end? on page 1 of the Wall Street Journal, Jan. 19, 1987. 1 4 banking sector created (slightly) positive abnormal liquidity before the crisis, but created significantly negative abnormal liquidity during and fter the crisis, representing behavior by banks that may have further fueled the crisis. Financial crisis 3 Russian debt crisis / LTCM bailout (1998Q3 1998Q4) Since its lineage in March 1994, hedge fund Long-Term Capital Management (LTCM) followed an arbitrage strategy that was admittedly market neutral, designed to make money regardless of whether prices were rising or falling. When Russia defaulted on its sovereign debt on August 17, 1998, investors fled from other government paper to the safe haven of U. S. treasuries.This flight to liquidity caused an unexpected outfit of spreads on supposedly low-risk portfolios. By the end of August 1998, LTCMs capital had dropped to $2. 3 billion, less than 50% of its December 1997 value, with assets standing at $126 billion. In the first three weeks of September, LTCMs capital dropped further to $600 million without shrinking the portfolio. Banks began to doubt its ability to meet margin calls. To prevent a potential systemic meltdown triggered by the collapse of the worlds largest hedge fund, the Federal Reserve Bank of New York form a $3. billion bail-out by LTCMs major creditors on September 23, 1998. In 1998Q4, many large banks had to take substantial write-offs as a result of losses on their investments. Figure 3 Panel C shows abnormal liquidity creation around the Russian debt crisis and LTCM bailout. The pattern shown in the graph is very different from the ones we have seen so far. Liquidity creation was abnormally negative before the crisis, but increasing. Liquidity creation increased further during the crisis, countercyclical behavior by banks that may have alleviated the crisis, and continued to grow after the crisis.This suggests that liquidity creation may have been too low entering the crisis and returned to normal levels a few accommodate after the end of the crisis. Financial crisis 4 Bursting of the dot. com bubble and Sept. 11 terrorist attack (2000Q2 2002Q3) The dot. com bubble was a speculative stock price bubble that was built up during the mid to late 1990s. During this period, many internet-based companies, commonly referred to as dot. coms, were founded. Rapidly increasing stock prices and widely available venture capital created an environs in which 15 any of these companies seemed to focus largely on increasing market share. At the height of the boom, it seemed possible for dot. coms to go public and raise substantial amounts of money even if they had never acquire any profits, and in some cases had not even earned any revenues. On March 10, 2000, the Nasdaq composite index peaked at more than double its value just a year before. After the bursting of the bubble, many dot. coms ran out of capital and were acquired or filed for bankruptcy (examples of the latter include WorldCom and Pets. com). The U. S. economy sta rted to slow down and business nvestments began falling. The September 11, 2001 terrorist attacks may have exacerbated the stock market downturn by adversely affecting investor sentiment. By 2002Q3, the Nasdaq index had fallen by 78%, wiping out $5 trillion in market value of mostly technology firms. Figure 3 Panel D shows how abnormal liquidity creation behaved before, during, and after the bursting of the dot. com bubble and the Sept. 11 terrorist attacks. The graph shows that before the crisis period, liquidity creation moved from displaying a negative abnormal value to displaying a positive abnormal value at the time the bubble burst.During the crisis, liquidity creation declined somewhat and hovered around the time trend by the time the crisis was over. After the crisis, liquidity creation slowly started to pick up again. Financial crisis 5 Subprime lending crisis (2007Q3 ? ) The subprime lending crisis has been characterized by agitation in financial markets as banks have exp erienced difficulty in selling loans in the syndicated loan market and in securitizing loans. Banks also seem to be reluctant to provide credit they appear to have cut back their lending to firms and individuals, and have also been reticent to lend to each other.Risk premia have increased as evidenced by a higher premium over treasuries for mortgages and other bank products. Some banks have experienced massive losses in capital. For example, Citicorp had to raise about $40 billion in equity to cover subprime lending and other losses. Massive losses at Countrywide resulted in a takeover by Bank of America. Bear Stearns suffered a fatal loss in confidence and was sold at a fire-sale price to J. P. Morgan Chase with the Federal Reserve guaranteeing $29 billion in potential losses. Washington Mutual, the sixth-largest bank, became the biggest bank failure in the U.S. financial history. J. P. Morgan Chase purchased the banking business while the rest of the organization filed for bankrup tcy. The Federal Reserve intervened in some 16 unprecedented ways in the market, extending its safety-net privileges to investment banks. In addition to lowering the discount rate sharply, it also began holding mortgage-backed securities and lending directly to investment banks. Subsequently, IndyMac Bank was seized by the FDIC after it suffered substantive losses and depositors had started to run on the bank. This failure is expected to cost the FDIC $4 billion $8 billion.The FDIC intends to sell the bank. Congress also recently passed legislation to provide Freddie Mac and Fannie Mae with straight-out credit lines and possible equity break inions to prop up these troubled organizations, which are considered too big to fail. Figure 3 Panel E shows abnormal liquidity creation before and during the first part of the subprime lending crisis. The graph suggests that liquidity creation displayed a high positive abnormal value that was increasing before the crisis hit, with abnormal l iquidity creation around $0. 0 trillion entering the crisis, decreasing substantially after the crisis hit. A striking fact about this crisis compared to the other crises is the relatively high build-up of positive abnormal liquidity creation prior to the crisis. 4. 4. Behavior of some liquidity creation components around the two banking crises It is of particular interest to examine the behavior of some selected components of liquidity creation around the banking crises. As discussed above (Section 4. 3), numerous papers have focused on the credit crunch, examining lending behavior.These studies generally find that mortgage and business lending started to decline significantly during the crisis. Here we contrast the credit crunch experience with the current subprime lending crisis, and increase the components of liquidity creation that are examined. Rather than focusing on mortgages and business loans, we examine the two liquidity creation components that include these items semi -liquid assets (primarily mortgages) and illiquid assets (primarily business loans). In addition, we analyze two other components of liquidity creation.We examine the behavior of liquid assets to address whether a decrease (increase) in semi-liquid assets and / or illiquid assets tended to be accompanied by an increase (decrease) in liquid assets. We also analyze the behavior of illiquid off-balance sheet guarantees (primarily loan commitments) to address whether illiquid assets and illiquid off-balance sheet guarantees move in tandem around banking crises and whether changes in one are more pronounced than the other. Figure 4 Panels A and B show the abnormal amount of four liquidity creation components around 17 he credit crunch and the subprime lending crisis, respectively. For ease of comparison, the components are not weighted by weights of +? (illiquid assets and illiquid off-balance sheet guarantees), 0 (semiliquid assets), and ? (liquid assets). The abnormal amounts are obtai ned by detrending and deseasonalizing each liquidity creation component. Figure 4 Panel A shows that abnormal semi-liquid assets decreased slightly during the credit crunch, while abnormal illiquid assets and especially abnormal illiquid guarantees dropped significantly and turned negative.This picture suggests that these components fell increasingly below the trendline. The dramatic drop in abnormal illiquid assets and abnormal illiquid off-balance sheet guarantees (which carry positive weights) helps explain the significant decrease in abnormal liquidity creation during the credit crunch shown in Figure 3 Panel B. Figure 4 Panel B shows that these four components of abnormal liquidity creation were above the trendline before and during the subprime lending crisis.Illiquid assets and especially off-balance sheet guarantees move further and further above the trendline before the crisis, which helps explain the dramatic buildup in abnormal liquidity creation before the subprime lendi ng crisis shown in Figure 3 Panel E. All four components of abnormal liquidity creation continued to increase at the beginning of the crisis. After the first quarter of the crisis, illiquid off-balance sheet guarantees showed a significant decrease, which helps explain the decrease in abnormal liquidity creation in Figure 3 Panel E.On the balance sheet, during the final quarter of the sample period (the third quarter of the crisis), abnormal semi-liquid and illiquid assets declined, while abnormal liquid assets increased. 4. 5. General conclusions from the results What do we learn from the various graphs in the previous analyses that indicate intertemporal patterns of liquidity creation and selected liquidity creation components around five financial crises? First, across all the financial crises, there seems to have been a significant build-up or drop-off of abnormal liquidity creation before the crisis.This is consistent with the notion that crises may be preceded by either too mu ch or too little liquidity creation, although at this stage we offer this as tentative food for thought rather than as a conclusion. Second, there seem to be two main differences between banking crises and market-related crises. 18 The banking crises, namely the credit crunch and the subprime lending crisis, were both preceded by positive abnormal liquidity creation by banks, while two out of the three market-related crises were preceded by negative abnormal liquidity creation.In addition, during the two banking crises, the crises themselves seem to have exerted a noticeable influence on the pattern of aggregate liquidity creation by banks. only when prior to the credit crunch, abnormal liquidity creation was positive and had started to trend upward, but reversed job and plunged quite substantially to become negative during and after the crisis. Just prior to the subprime lending crisis, aggregate liquidity creation was again abnormally positive and trending up, but began to decli ne during the crisis, although it remains abnormally high by historical standards.The other crises, which are less directly related to banks, did not seem to exhibit such noticeable impact. Third, liquidity creation has both decreased during crises (e. g. , the 1990-1992 credit crunch) and increased during crises (e. g. , the 1998 Russian debt crisis / LTCM bailout). Thus, liquidity creation likely both exacerbated and ameliorated the effects of crises. Fourth, off-balance sheet illiquid guarantees (primarily loan commitments) moved more than semi-liquid assets (primarily mortgages) and illiquid assets (primarily business loans) during banking crises.Fifth, while liquidity creation is generally thought of as a financial intermediation service with positive economic value at the level of the individual bank and individual borrower (see Diamond and Rajan 2000, 2001), our analysis hints at the humanity of a dark side to liquidity creation. Specifically, it may be more than coincidence that the subprime lending crisis was preceded by a very high level of positive abnormal aggregate liquidity creation by banks relative to historical levels.The notion that this may have contributed to the subprime lending crisis is consistent with the findings that banks adopted lax credit standards (see DellAriccia, Igan, and Laeven 2008, Keys, Mukherjee, Seru, and Vig 2008), which in turn could have led to an increase in credit availability and off-balance sheet guarantees. Thus, while Diamond and Rajan (2000, 2001) argue that financial fragility is needed to create liquidity, our analysis offers the intriguing possibility that the causality may be reversed as well too much liquidity creation may lead to financial fragility. 9 5. The effect of capital on banks competitive positions and profitability around financial crises This section focuses on the second goal of the paper examining how bank capital affects banks competitive positions and profitability around financial crises. We first explain our methodology and provide summary statistics. We then present and discuss the empirical results. In an additional check, we examine whether the stock return performance of high- and low-capital listed banks is consistent with the competitive position and profitability results for large banks.In another check, we generate some fake crises to analyze whether our findings hold during normal times as well. 5. 1. Empirical approach To examine whether banks with high capital ratios improve their competitive positions and profitability during financial crises, and if so, whether they are able to hold on to this improved performance after these crises, we focus on the behavior of individual banks rather than that of the banking sector as a whole.Because our analysis of aggregate liquidity creation by banks shows substantial differences across crises, we do not pool the data from all the crises but instead analyze each crisis separately. Our findings below that the coeffi cients of interest differ substantially across crises tend to justify this separate interference of the different crises. We use the following regression specification for each of the five crises ? PERFi,j = ? + ? 1 * EQRATi,j + B * Zi,j (1) where ?PERFi,j is the change in bank is performance around crisis j, EQRATi,j is the banks average capital ratio before the crisis, and Zi,j includes a set of control variables averaged over the pre-crisis period. All of these variables are discussed in Section 5. 2. Since we use a cross-sectional regression model, bank and year fixed effects are not included. In all regressions, t-statistics are based on robust standard errors. Given documented differences between large and small banks in terms of portfolio composition (e. g. Kashyap, Rajan, and Stein 2002, Berger, Miller, Petersen, Rajan, and Stein 2005) and the effect of capital on liquidity creation (Berger and Bouwman forthcoming), we split the sample into large and small banks, and run al l regressions separately for these two sets of banks. Large banks have gross total assets (GTA) exceeding $1 billion at the end of the quarter preceding the crisis and small banks have GTA up to 20 $1 billion at the end of that quarter. 5. 2. inconstant descriptions and summary statistics We use two measures of a banks performance competitive position and profitability.The banks competitive position is measured as the banks market share of general liquidity creation, i. e. , the dollar amount of liquidity created by the bank divided by the dollar amount of liquidity created by the industry. Our focus on the share of liquidity creation is a departure from the traditional focus on a banks market share of deposits. Liquidity creation is a more comprehensive measure of banking activities since it does not just consider one funding item but instead is based on all the banks on-balance sheet and off-balance sheet activities.To establish whether banks improve their competitive positions during the crisis, we define the change in liquidity creation market share, ? LCSHARE, as the banks average market share during the crisis minus its average market share over the eight quarters before the crisis, normalized by its average pre-crisis market share. To examine whether these banks hold on to their improved performance after the crisis, we also measure each banks average market share over the eight quarters after the crisis minus its average market share over the eight quarters before the crisis, again normalized by its average market share before the crisis.The second performance measure is the banks profitability, measured as the return on equity (ROE), i. e. , net income divided by stockholders equity. 23 To examine whether a bank improves its profitability during a crisis, we focus on the change in profitability, ? ROE, measured as the banks average ROE during the crisis minus the banks average ROE over the eight quarters before the crisis. 24 To analyze whether the bank is able to hold on to improved profitability, we focus on the banks average ROE over the eight quarters after the crisis minus its average ROE over the eight quarters before the crisis.To mitigate the influence of outliers, ? LCSHARE and ? ROE are winsorized at the 3% level. Furthermore, to ensure that average values are calculated based on a sufficient number of quarters, we 23 We use ROE, the banks net income divided by equity, rather than return on assets (ROA), net income divided by assets, since banks may have substantial off-balance sheet portfolios. Banks must allocate capital against every offbalance sheet activity they engage in. Hence, net income and equity both reflect the banks on-balance sheet and off-balance sheet activities.In contrast, ROA divides net income earned based on on-balance sheet and off-balance sheet activities merely by the size of the on-balance sheet activities. 24 We do not divide by the banks ROE before the crisis since ROE itself is already a s caled variable. 21 require that at least half of a banks pre-crisis / crisis / post-crisis observations are available for both performance measures around a crisis. Since the subprime lending crisis was still ongoing at the end of the sample period, we require that at least half of a banks pre-subprime crisis observations and all three quarters of its subprime crisis observations are available.The key exogenous variable is EQRAT, the banks capital ratio averaged over the eight quarters before the crisis. EQRAT is the ratio of equity capital to gross total assets, GTA. 25 The control variables include bank size, bank risk, bank holding company membership, local market competition, and proxies for the economic environment. Bank size is controlled for by including lnGTA, the log of GTA, in all regressions. In addition, we run regressions separately for large and small banks. We include the z-score to control for bank risk. 26 The z-score indicates the banks distance from default (e. g. Boyd, Graham, and Hewitt 1993), with higher values indicating that a bank is less likely to default. It is measured as a banks return on assets plus the equity capital/GTA ratio divided by the standard deviation of the return on assets over the eight quarters before the crisis. To control for bank holding company status, we include D-BHC, a gage variable that equals 1 if the bank was part of a bank holding company. Bank holding company membership may affect a banks competitive position because the holding company is required to act as a source of strength to all the banks it owns, and may also inject equity voluntarily when needed.In addition, other banks in the holding company provide cross-guarantees. Furthermore, Houston, James, and Marcus (1997) find that bank loan growth depends on BHC membership. We control for local market competition by including HERF, the bank-level HerfindahlHirschman index of deposit constriction for the markets in which the bank is p
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment